Skip to main content

What can legal academics add to the debate about private equity?

Dear Editor, 

In December 2015, Unite – Britain’s largest trade union – called on the UK government to investigate the ‘secretive machinations of private equity firms’ following the near-collapse of Fairline Boats, a Northamptonshire yacht-builder employing well over 400 people.[1] Unite’s demands were not new: as the economic influence of private equity firms has increased in Europe over the last few decades, so have the calls from unions, politicians and the media for regulators to intervene.

But it is not entirely clear what private equity’s critics want the regulators to do. 

More transparency perhaps? Voluntary guidelines – adopted in 2007 by the UK’s private equity trade association, the British Private Equity and Venture Capital Association (BVCA) – already mandate listed company-like disclosures for the largest private equity-owned companies,[2] but for smaller businesses (like Fairline Boats) it is far from obvious why companies owned by private equity should be treated any differently to any other privately-owned company, all of whom are already subject to statutory public disclosures.

Meanwhile, private equity’s critics in the UK and, probably more importantly, other parts of Europe, have given impetus to the European Commission who, as part of its response to the financial crisis, introduced far reaching EU-wide regulation of the ‘alternative investment funds’ industry.[3] Taking up the cause of transparency, the Commission required greater disclosure by buyout houses taking over larger EU companies, and outlawed some types of ‘asset stripping’ in the two years following the acquisition.[4] How effective these changes turn out to be, remains to be seen, but there certainly does not seem to have been much background work by policy-makers to justify the new rules or assess their impact.

That may not be surprising, given the perceived need for ‘quick fixes’ after the Financial Crisis (even though there was no convincing evidence that private equity played any part in causing the crisis, or adding to the systemic risks which exacerbated it).  But it is also notable that regulators had little home-grown corporate governance law scholarship to draw upon in designing their regulatory response.[5]

It is true that there is considerable research on the economic impact of private equity, including from the LSE’s own Abraaj Group Professor in Finance and Private Equity, Ulf Axelson.[6] On the whole, academics have concluded that private equity-backed companies are more efficient than their publicly listed counterparts, and perhaps also than their privately-owned peers.[7] Their impact on wages and employment remains somewhat controversial, although there is no convincing academic support for the short-term asset stripping accusations often levelled at the industry.[8] 

However, industry-wide quantitative performance studies, though important, are not going to give the full picture, and the effect that private equity firms have on governance structures is under-researched, especially in relation to the mechanisms behind the ‘machinations’ that determine decisions for stakeholders.

More research in this area is vital, because policy-makers have to design regulation with the benefit of evidence-based theoretical models.  But corporate governance scholars, at least in the legal academy, have spent much more time thinking about widely-held companies than they have about those which are closely-held.  That is understandable (and presents a very worthwhile and interesting research topic), but we need to help policy-makers think about private companies – including fairly small ones. 

As anyone who has taken an undergraduate course in company law will know, most academic theories of corporate governance focus on ‘agency costs’: the temptation to ‘steal’ or ‘shirk’ when (in Adam Smiths’ terms)[9] one person is charged with looking after another’s money.[10] However, many academics accept that, when stakeholders have good and reasonably symmetric access to information and the right incentives, they will bargain for optimal terms, mitigating (although probably not eliminating) the agency costs implicit in the delegation of power.[11] It is also commonly argued (although by no means universally accepted)[12] that the most efficient companies will be created when shareholders are the ultimate beneficiaries of the efforts of those in charge, and (if they are equipped to do so) are allowed to bargain freely for the agency-cost mitigating structures which suit them best.[13]

However, the UK’s corporate governance framework, especially as it applies to private companies, is muddled.  On the one hand, it pays attention to the ‘freedom to contract’ paradigm implied by the theory described above; but it is also peppered with apparently mandatory rules.[14] It is not always clear who these rules are designed to protect, and many of them turn out to be contractible in any event.[15] Justifications for mandatory rules in widely-held companies may not apply to closely-held companies, with the consequence that designing optimal corporate governance frameworks in this environment may be more costly than it needs to be, and efficient outcomes may be thwarted. 

On the other hand, if there is a case for mandatory rules designed to protect other stakeholders who do not have a seat at the table when private company constitutions are written, that case needs to be articulated on a sound theoretical footing.  If the case is made, the mandatory rules which it implies will, no doubt, be quite different to the ones we have.  But if that case fails, it certainly does not undermine the case for protecting those stakeholders in other ways: through, for example, enhanced employment protection rights, or tougher regulations prohibiting pollution or other actions giving rise to externalities which rational shareholders would not internalise.  That is, after all, the more usual way in which we protect third parties.

In the end Fairline Boats (now renamed Fairline Yachts) seems to have been saved,[16] although with significant job losses.  That may or may not have been the best available outcome for society at large, but it is not clear what legal changes, if any, could have led to a better one.  If any part of the answer to that question lies with the UK’s corporate governance laws (and, perhaps just as importantly, if it does not), then legal academics should step up to the plate.

Yours,

Simon Witney,

PhD Candidate
London School of Economics


(1 Mar 2016)



[1] http://www.unitetheunion.org/news/call-for-probe-into-private-equity-firms-as-northamptonshire-boat-builder-goes-into-administration/ [Accessed 9 February 2016]

[2] Information on the Guidelines and their enforcement by the semi-independent Private Equity Reporting Group is available here: http://privateequityreportinggroup.co.uk/. 

[3] The Alternative Investment Fund Managers Directive (2011/61/EU).

[4] See Directive 2011/61/EU, Articles 26-30, implemented in the UK by the Alternative Investment Fund Managers Regulations 2013 (SI 2013/1773) Regulations 34-44.

[5] A very important contribution was subsequently made (in 2013) by the LSE’s Carsten Gerner-Beuerle, Philipp Paech and Edmund Philipp Schuster, who undertook a comprehensive academic comparison of directors’ duties and liabilities across the EU for the European Commission:  http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/company/docs/board/2013-study-analysis_en.pdf.

[6] See http://personal.lse.ac.uk/axelson/ for Ulf’s details and selected publications list.

[7] See, for example, Y. Alperovych, K. Amess and M. Wright, ‘Private equity firm experience and buyout vendor source: What is their impact on efficiency?’, European Journal of Operational Research, (2013) 228, 601-611 for evidence from the UK; and S. Davis, J. Lerner, J. Haltiwanger, J. Miranda and R. Jarmin, ‘Private equity, jobs and productivity’, in A. Gurung and J. Lerner (eds), The Global Impact of Private Equity Report 2009, Globalization of Alternative Investments, Working Papers Volume 2, World Economic Forum, 25-46, for data from the US.

[8] A good overview of academic research is included in J. Gilligan and M. Wright, ‘Private equity demystified: An explanatory guide’, 2014, 3rd edition, ICAEW (available at http://www.icaew.com/en/technical/corporate-finance/financing-change/private-equity-demystified-an-explanatory-guide-160216) – see the Appendix at pages 176-198.

[9] See Adam Smith, ‘The Wealth of Nations’, 1776, Cannan Edition (Modern Library, New York, 1937), at page 700.

[10] The most quoted source for this analysis is M. Jensen and W. Meckling, Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure, 1976, 3 Journal of Financial Economics, 305-360.

[11] See, for example, F. Easterbrook and D. Fischel, ‘The Economic Structure of Corporate Law’, 1991, Harvard University Press.

[12] For a thought-provoking contemporary view, arguing that directors should pursue a societal purpose, insulated from profit maximising shareholders, see Will Hutton, ‘How Good We Can Be’, 2015, Little, Bown, at pages 137-142.

[13] For a clear and entertaining exposition see S Bainbridge, ‘Director Primacy: The Means and Ends of Corporate Governance’, 2003, 97 Northwestern University Law Review, 547. 

[14] I have written elsewhere about some of the problems for non-executive directors posed by the mandatory rules on conflicts of interest: see S. Witney, Corporate opportunities law and the non-executive director, 2016, Journal of Corporate Law Studies (http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/14735970.2015.1117349).

[15] Perhaps the most famous example is the House of Lords decision in Bushell v Faith [1970] AC 1099, in which it was held that the contractual nature of company law (allowing the company’s constitution to decide which shares get to vote on any particular resolution) allowed directors to entrench themselves with weighted voting rights even though a mandatory rule says that they will always be removable by ordinary resolution.

[16] See The Guardian, 26 January 2016, Fairline Boats former staff 'queuing at gates' to work after Russian takeover,  http://www.theguardian.com/business/2016/jan/26/fairline-boats-staff-queuing-gates-work-russian-takeover [Accessed 9/2/16].

x

Comments

  1. I've been enjoying the blog very much. You pay more careful attention to CJEU decisions about copyright than any other blogger that I have found, which is very useful for me as someone interested in copyright. It is also great to have a perspective from outside the UK.mosscolella.com/michigan-motorcycle-accident-lawyers/

    ReplyDelete
  2. hey, I really like this post and had a fun time reading it. So thank you so much for posting it online on your blog and I am looking forward to more.lawyer in Dubai


    ReplyDelete

Post a Comment

Popular posts from this blog

UK/EU Referendum: Are there alternatives to Membership?

Dear Editor,  Within the next few months, the UK electorate will have to decide on the UK’s relationship with the EU. In February, the Heads of State of the EU Member States will discuss to what extent Cameron’s demands can be accommodated in a new settlement. In June (probably) the renewed relationship between the UK and the EU shall be put to the UK electorate in a yes/no referendum. This timing already suggests that Treaty change (i.e. to the TFEU) is out of the order – 4 months is nowhere long enough for 28 national parliaments to ratify the changes, and the Member States that are so constitutionally required to hold a referendum (even presuming that they all agree with the new compromise). It seems that any reforms would have to be legally enshrined as changes to secondary legislation. Such changes, however, require the consent of the European Commission and the European Parliament, which is difficult to be secured given their general pro-integration stance. It will remain to

A Right to "Truth" in the War on Terror

Dear Editor,  One of the most disturbing features of the “War on Terror” is Guantanamo Bay. At the end of October 2015, Shaker Aamer, the last UK citizen detained there, was finally released and allowed to reunite with his family, after 14 years of incarceration without charge. As a lawyer committed to the principle of the rule of law and the protection of human rights through the UK and European court systems, I wondered how long it would be before Mr Aamer took legal action against the UK Government for complicity in his torture. We’ve already seen several cases at the European Court of Human Rights regarding British violations in the Iraq war. For example, in Al-Skeini, [1]   it was alleged that five Iraqi citizens were killed by British troops in the UK-occupied Basra; the sixth victim was arrested by British troops and taken to a UK detention facility where he was allegedly mistreated and killed. In Al-Jedda, [2]   the applicant was detained at a British-run dete